• Comment: Not quite enough independent, significant coverage listed to show why this is notable enough for Wikipedia. WikiOriginal-9 (talk) 20:01, 6 November 2023 (UTC)

The GNM-method is the generalized version of the NM-method. The latter was developed by Naszodi and Mendonca (2021).,[1] and first applied by Naszodi and Mendonca (2019),[2] before being used in some other papers [3], [4], [5], [6], [7] [8], [9]. Whereas the GNM-method was developed by Naszodi (2021)[10] and applied by Naszodi and Mendonca (2023) [11]

Application edit

The GNM-method can be applied to study various phenomena including assortative mating along multiple traits.

"To gain insight on the importance of analyzing sorting along multiple traits, e.g., race and education level, consider a hypothetical society with all men and all women marry someone from the opposite sex from their own generation when being young adults. There are two generations in this society: the early generation and the late generation. The education level of the late generation is not different from that of the early generation. Moreover, people of a particular race tend to have higher educational attainment than people of another race in both of the generations.

In addition, we make the following assumptions: (i) those belonging to the late generation are exactly as picky about spousal education as the members of the early generation were when they were young adults; and (ii) barriers to racial intermarriage have been reduced from one generation to the next, i.e., fewer members in the late generation have opposed marrying someone of a different race compared to those in the early generation. Under these assumptions one may mistakenly conclude that the degree of educational sorting is decreasing in this hypothetical society. This error can occur if changes in sorting along race are not properly controlled for.

Conversely, suppose that aggregate preferences for well-educated partners are stronger in the late generation than they were in the early generation. Further, let us assume that marital racial preferences are exactly the same in the two generations. Then, one can mistakenly find that racial homophily is on the rise in this hypothetical society by studying inter-racial marriages without controlling for the increase in the degree of sorting along the educational. " (see Naszodi and Mendonca 2023[11]).

Comparison with the NM-method edit

While the NM-method is suitable for constructing counterfactual joint distributions of a one-dimensional pair of traits (e.g. husband's education level and wife's education level),[1] the GNM-method can be applied to multidimensional pairs of traits (e.g., husband's education level and race; wife's education level and race).[11]

The counterfactual constructed by the NM-method can be used to decompose inter-generational changes in the prevalence of (educational) homogamy into the effects due to changes in (i) the structural availability (e.g., the educational distribution of marriageable men and women), (ii) the non-structural factor (e.g., aggregate marital preferences over spousal education, social barriers to marrying out of one's educational group, social marital norms), and (iii) the interaction of changing structural availability and the non-structural factor.[1]

The NM-method provides a unique solution to the counterfactual table (if the counterfactual is not impossible to obtain).[1] Therefore, the components calculated with the counterfactual decompositions based on the NM-method are scalar-valued.

Unlike the NM-method, the GNM-method results in a set of counterfactual tables. Therefore, it provides an interval for the components if being used for counterfactual decompositions.[11]

Comparison with alternative methods developed to analyze sorting along multiple traits edit

The GNM-method is not the only method developed with the aim of analyzing sorting along more than one trait. For instance, the papers by Chiappori, Oreffice, and Quintana-Domeque (2011) [12] , Galichon and Salanié (2021)[13], Naszodi and Mendonca (2022)[4], and Rosenfeld (2008)[14] propose alternative methods for the same purpose.

"Chiappori et al (2011)[12] provide a closed-form solution of a multidimensional matching model and then they test predictions of how spouses trade off education and non-smoking. In the model by Galichon and Salanié (2021)[13], the surplus from a marriage match depends on the partners' education, race and some other traits unobserved by the econometrician. In the full-fledged micro-founded model of Naszodi and Mendonca (2022)[4], matches are made with the Gale-Shapley algorithm and each individual is assumed to sort along two characteristics: the marriageable person's educational attainment, and his or her reservation point (used as a proxy for the unobserved traits of the person and empirically identified by the search criteria of a group of dating site users). Finally, Rosenfeld (2008)[14] examines sorting along three dimensions (education, race, and religion) in the US." (see Naszodi and Mendonca 2023[11]).

The distinctive feature of the GNM-method compared to its alternatives is that it builds on a different definition of unchanged non-structural factor (i.e., the driving factor of the prevalence of homogamy other than the structural factor representing changes in the educational distributions of marriageable men and women). According to the GNM, the non-structural factor is constant if the generalized version of the Liu-Lu-indicator[15] is kept fixed. (The original Liu-Lu-indicator is the slightly modified version of the Coleman-index defined by Eq. 15 in Coleman 1958.[16])

The (generalized) LL-indicator is different from those indicators that form the basis of the alternatives to the GNM-method, such as the regression coefficient (applied by Greenwood et al 2014[17]), the marital surplus (developed by Choo and Siow 2006[18], while generalized and applied by Chiappori et al. 2011[12], Galichon and Salanié 2021[13]), and the odds-ratio (applied by Rosenfeld 2008[14] inter alia). See Naszodi (2023)[9] for a systematic comparison among a comprehensive set of indicators.

Implementation edit

The GNM-method is implemented in Matlab and R. It can be downloaded from Mendeley.[19] The NM-method is implemented in Excel, Visual Basic, R[20] and also in Stata.[19]

See also edit

References edit

  1. ^ a b c d Naszodi, A.; Mendonca, F. (2021). "A new method for identifying the role of marital preferences at shaping marriage patterns". Journal of Demographic Economics. 1 (1): 1–27. doi:10.1017/dem.2021.1.
  2. ^ Naszodi, A.; Mendonca, F. (2019). "Like marries like". Fairness Policy Brief Series. Archived from the original on 2022-04-06.
  3. ^ Naszodi, A. (2021). "Decomposition scheme matters more than you may think". arXiv:2104.09141 [econ.GN].
  4. ^ a b c Naszodi, A.; Mendonca, F. (2022). "Changing educational homogamy: Shifting preferences or evolving educational distribution?". Journal of Demographic Economics. 1 (1): 1–29. doi:10.1017/dem.2022.21.
  5. ^ Naszodi, A. (2023). "What do surveys say about the historical trend of inequality and the applicability of two table-transformation methods?". arXiv:2303.05895 [econ.GN].
  6. ^ Naszodi, A. (2023). "The iterative proportional fitting algorithm and the NM-method: solutions for two different sets of problems". arXiv:2303.05515 [econ.GN].
  7. ^ Naszodi, A. (2023). "Direct comparison or indirect comparison via a series of counterfactual decompositions?". arXiv:2303.04905 [econ.GN].
  8. ^ Naszodi, A. (2022). "Hogyan szálazzuk szét a megfigyelhető változások okait?". Közgazdasági Szemle. 69 (11): 1407–1432. doi:10.18414/KSZ.2022.11.1407.
  9. ^ a b Naszodi, A. (2023). "Historical trend of homophily: U-shaped or not U-shaped? Or, how would you set a criterion to decide which criterion is better to choose a criterion?". arXiv:2305.00231 [econ.GN].
  10. ^ Naszodi, A. (2021). "A new method for identifying changing marital preferences for race and education level". arXiv:2103.06991v1 [econ.GN].
  11. ^ a b c d e Naszodi, A.; Mendonca, F. (2023). "A new method for identifying what Cupid's invisible hand is doing. Is it spreading color blindness while turning us more "picky" about spousal education?". arXiv:2103.06991 [econ.GN].
  12. ^ a b c Chiappori, P.-A.; Oreffice, S.; Quintana-Domeque, C. (2011). "Matching with a Handicap: The Case of Smoking in the Marriage Market". Working Papers No. 2011-017.
  13. ^ a b c Galichon, A.; Salanié, B. (2021). Matching with Trade-offs: Revealed Preferences over Competing Characteristics (Technical report).
  14. ^ a b c Rosenfeld, M.J. (2008). "Racial, educational, and religious endogamy in the United States: A comparative historical perspective". Social Forces. 87 (1): 1–32. doi:10.1353/sof.0.0077. S2CID 18300347.
  15. ^ Liu, H.; Lu, J. (2006). "Measuring the degree of assortative mating". Economics Letters. 92 (3): 317–322. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2006.03.010.
  16. ^ Coleman, J. (1958). "Relational Analysis: The Study of Social Organizations with Survey Methods". Human Organization. 17 (4): 28–36. doi:10.17730/humo.17.4.q5604m676260q8n7.
  17. ^ Greenwood, J.; Guner, N.; Kocharkov, G.; Santos, C. (2014). "Marry Your Like: Assortative Mating and Income Inequality" (PDF). American Economic Review. 104 (5): 348–53. doi:10.1257/aer.104.5.348.
  18. ^ Choo, E.; Siow, A. (2006). "Who Marries Whom and Why". Journal of Political Economy. 114 (1): 175–201. doi:10.1086/498585. S2CID 13464761.
  19. ^ a b Naszodi, Anna; Mendonca, Francisco (2023). "Code for "A NEW METHOD FOR IDENTIFYING WHAT CUPID'S INVISIBLE HAND IS DOING. IS IT SPREADING COLOR BLINDNESS WHILE TURNING US MORE "PICKY" ABOUT SPOUSAL EDUCATION?"". 1. Mendeley. doi:10.17632/95k6mmrxvg. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  20. ^ Naszodi, Anna; Mendonca, Francisco (2021). "Code for A NEW METHOD FOR IDENTIFYING THE ROLE OF MARITAL PREFERENCES AT SHAPING MARRIAGE PATTERNS". 2. Mendeley. doi:10.17632/x2ry7bcm95. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)